Tag Archives: inequality

The Gender Wage Share: History and Implications

This post traces the gender wage share and women’s increasing share of the total wage pool in Australia since the mid-1980s. Women as a whole currently earn just 38% of all wage earnings in Australia. This is a product of the aggregate of the gender wage gap and the difference in labour force participation, and by my calculation amounts to a difference of around $200bn a year.

In a previous post I argued that the magnitude of the difference constituted a significant macroeconomic flow with an important role in the reproduction of society – and of gender relations in particular.

The rationale for the use of gender wage share data and the conclusions drawn are set out in that previous post. Here I want to consider the changes over time in those gender economic aggregates, and the implications of those changes for our understanding of inequality.

Time Series

The graph below shows the female share of “total earnings” in the ABS Average Weekly Earnings data from 1984 to the present. This is a simple calculation based on average employment earnings multiplied by the number of workers.

It is important to note that “earnings” here refers only to employment income. In the ABS data it is called “total earnings” because it includes overtime – as opposed to ordinary time earnings (which is also in the data set). However, that should not be confused with a total of all earnings, which could include social security payments, investment income or other mixed income. The World Economic Database now has this all-earnings data for Australia, but the time series is more limited and contains a bold assumption that mixed income is shared in the same proportion as other income. In any case, the results are similar with the data for 2019 showing a female share of 36.6% of total earnings, while my data has the female share at 38%.

Line graph of Female Share of Total Earning
1984 - 28.6%
2020 - 38%

The graph shows three phases in a history of an overall increase in women’s share of the total wage pool over the last 36 years. From the mid-1980s through to 1992, there was a significant increase in women’s share going from 28.6% of wages to 33% of the total wage pool. This was based on a small narrowing (2 percentage points) of the full-time gender wage gap, but a more significant increase in women’s share of jobs – going from 37.9% of employment in 1984 to 42.6% in November 1992.

After 1992, women’s share of the wage pool continued to increase, but at a slower rate until 2012. There is a change in ABS data series here so some data discontinuity, but women’s share of total wages has grown significantly since then from 34.9% of all wage earnings in 2012 to 38.5% in May 2021. This has largely been on the back of a decrease in the full-time gender wage gap (4.5 percentage points) and a more modest (1.9 percentage point) increase in the share of jobs.

These drivers are shown in the following graph which creates indexes showing changes in the gender wage share alongside the proportion of the workforce who are women (participation) and the changes in proportionate remuneration (that is, average female full-time earnings as a proportion of male full-time earnings). This last index is just a different presentation of the commonly-cited gender wage gap.

As can be seen, the increased gender wage share tracks most closely with increased participation. However, between through the 1990s and early 2000s the wage share is dragged down below the participation rate increase by a stagnation of the remuneration gap (evident in the F-T wage proportion) from 1992 to 2007, followed by a widening of this gap after the onset of the global financial crisis in 2007. From 2014 this dynamic largely reversed with the decreasing remuneration gap accelerating the female wage share faster than the increase in participation.

Index of Gender Wage Share, Gender Wage Gap (F/T Ordinary) and Participation (female proportion of jobs).

The overall trend of an increase in women’s share of the earnings is not unique to Australia. The World Inequality Report 2022 data shows that women’s share increased between 1990 and 2020 in most regions of the world (with China being the notable exception).

Implications

This gender wage share data has implications for how we understand and speak about inequality. With the female share of the total Australian wage pool growing significantly and (relatively) steadily since the 1980s we have seen a move towards greater gender equality (at least in terms of labour market incomes). Yet, particularly following Piketty’s work, it is now a fairly standard claim on the left that inequality has increased since the early 1980s.

This claim of increased inequality is certainly true based on the usual measures of household income (the data is well summarised by ACOSS/UNSW), but given the data on the female wage share we need to recognise that claims about increasing inequality are gendered, or at least gender-blind, statements. They are not wrong, but they are privileging particular data and the gender-blind category of the household over other standpoints and data which focus on women’s income.

Or to put it another way, such measurements of increasing inequality are based on (and promote) views of society as households stratified along a continuum, rather than as structured by gender (and other) inequalities.

Further, the gender wage share data puts a different light on the left critique of neoliberal or right-wing labour market policies. The standard argument is that the removal of labour protections, penalty rates and working conditions, and the increasing precariousness of work are likely to impact disproportionately on women who are in the most marginal and disempowered jobs. (See for instance Alison Pennington’s excellent critique of last year’s Industrial Relations Bill).

There is no argument from me with these critiques of the neoliberal reforms of the last 30 years. But what the gender wage data shows is that these neoliberal advances have been counterbalanced and ultimately outweighed by the movement of women into the labour market in greater numbers and some closing of the gender wage gap.

This is not an argument for complacency, but rather to argue for a more nuanced and multi-level analysis of our analysis of inequality. There are other forces beyond neoliberalism which are also shaping economic outcomes.

Caveats and Conclusion

While greater gender equality would (and should) normally be seen as a good thing, the increased female wage share is not unproblematic. Firstly, it should be recognised that this is an increasing share of a proportionately decreasing pie as the labour share of total income has been decreasing over much of the period. (See the Journal of Political Economy’s Special Issue on the Declining Labour Share).

Further, it must also be recognised that, in an era of stagnating wages and increasing cost of living (in particular, rapidly rising housing costs), one of the drivers of increasing female workforce participation is the need for households to have two incomes to stay afloat.

Unequal symbol with words "inequality - not what you think"

Ultimately though, regardless of these caveats on the increasing gender equality story, what the gender wage share data shows is the importance of standpoint and the questions we ask about inequality (and much else). Asking questions about structural inequality (such as gender, class, race, geography) provides different perspectives and different conclusions than the traditional focus on household income – a theme I will return to in future posts about other structural inequalities.

And of course, there is also the sheer size of the $200bn gap in the gender wage share, which is important in its own right (and not visible in the mainstream statistics).

Massively Underestimating Inequality? The Problem of Housing Incomes

Just before Christmas the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) published statistics on Personal Income in Australia for 2018-19. The data, based on income tax returns, provides a window on inequality – and unusually for the ABS, the data is individual rather than household-based.

The ABS summary data tells us that the ACT has the highest median income and Tasmania the lowest. The top 1% of income earners accounted for 9.5% of all personal income, while the top 10% took one-third of all income. As the graph below shows, it also tells us which local government areas have the highest median income.

Income Inequality by LGA

I was also interested to see some quirky South Australian patterns. Roxby Downs, with miners’ incomes and few pensioners, had a stand out median income ($95,196) – way more than the second highest local government area (Walkerville). SA and Tasmania also had fewer people in the highest income bracket (quartile), which partly accounts for the lower average income in those states.

Problems in the Data

However, despite such insights, this headline ABS data is incomplete and is arguably significantly underestimating inequality.

Most obviously the data is incomplete because it does not include those on very low incomes or government payments who don’t have to file a tax return. Accordingly, it is a very truncated income spectrum. Further, household income may look very different to personal income depending on whether there are one or more breadwinners. As the ABS notes, their Household Income and Wealth survey data is a much better base for analysis.

But there is a more fundamental problem (in both ABS data sets) that leads to underestimating inequality, and that is the treatment of housing income.

Housing is important in income terms because different housing tenures create differences in effective (actual purchasing power) household income. This flows through to very different living standards and chances of wealth accumulation. The two key issues, which are not captured in the basic income data, are imputed rents and capital gains.

Imputed Rent

Tenants pay rent to landlords for the use of a house (the provision of housing services) and this appears as income for the landlord. However, a home owner-occupier pays no rent, yet is clearly in receipt of a “housing service” – the provision of shelter and amenity. This issue has long been recognised as a problem in economic statistics. In national accounting, it is a problem because renting out an existing house would suddenly add income and “product” to the market, when in fact nothing more is produced – the house provides the same amount of housing service regardless of whether it is rented or owner-occupied.

The economist’s solution to this issue is to impute a value for rent – that is, assign a value of income as if the home-owner pays rent to themselves. This recognises the value of the housing service being enjoyed as in-kind income by the owner-occupier. In Australia’s national accounts, some 7.7% of Gross Domestic Product is the value of rent imputed to home owner-occupiers (my calculation from ABS data).

Theoretically, the accounts could go further and impute a value for the other services produced within that house (meals, cleaning, counselling, sex) – but that is another story (and a PhD).

However, in terms of housing income, the imputed value of the rent should be added to the income of home owner-occupiers to better reflect the differences in the purchasing power of income between renters and home-owners. This is similar to the common practice in poverty and inequality research of using “after-housing” income as the benchmark. In this case though, the adjustment happens on the income rather than consumption side of the household budget.

We will see below the potential difference this can make to inequality data.

Capital Gains

The second major problem in the basic income distribution data is that it does not include capital gains. Total income includes wages and all employment earnings, income from unincorporated businesses, and investment and superannuation earnings, but not the increase in the value of capital assets.

In an earlier post, I noted a study by Lisa Adkins and others that argued that asset price inflation means that capital gains, capital income and inter-generational transfers are the preeminent drivers of inequality. Further, the authors argue that housing, more than any other asset class, is driving the dramatic increase in net wealth among high-income households. This is so important that they present a new categorisation of class in Australia based on asset ownership.

Of course, there are cash flow problems and costs/barriers to realising (spending) these non-cash incomes, but the fact remains that if renters and home owner-occupiers spent the exactly the same on non-housing items each week, the home-owner would be saving more and accumulating wealth which the renter would not. Their effective incomes are quite different.

Combining Income and Wealth Data

Again, we will see below the potential difference that including capital gains as income could make to inequality data, but including this (and imputed rent) also begins to address a key problem common in presentations which treat income and wealth inequality as different data sets. As I have previously posted, many low-income households do not have low wealth, and some high-income households do not have high wealth – and there are policy problems in shaping policy responses simply around low income.

The ABS did significant work on these issues in 2013 and developed a concept of low economic resource households (defined as those simultaneously in the lowest 40% of income and wealth) – and also included imputed rent in income calculations. However, it was a sideline to the main income data and the ABS has not really continued this work. Further, the concept is clunky to use and has not really been taken up by anti-poverty or inequality researchers (for instance, the World Inequality Database and the flagship ACOSS inequality report both largely present income and wealth data separately and do not include non-cash incomes).

That said, the ABS does still publish stand-alone estimates of imputed rent, and also household wealth from which capital gains can be calculated. Incorporating this non-cash housing income into income data may then be one step in integrating wealth and income inequality data into something more usable.

The Average Renter/Homeowner

The impact of the above can be seen in the following calculation, which is based on the baldest averages in the ABS Household Income and Wealth data for 2017-18.

The average household disposable income for homeowners (both mortgagees and full-owners[1]) was $1,972 per week, by comparison with $1,508 for all renters. In this standard comparison, the average homeowner earned 1.3 times more income than the average renter.

According to the ABS data, the average net rent imputation (that is, imputed rent minus housing costs) was $248 per week. This would take the average homeowner’s enhanced income to $2,220 per week – or 1.5 times that of the average renter.

The ABS data also shows that the average value of owner-occupied dwellings was $755,000 in 2017-18. Two years earlier, it was $673,000. Assuming that most of that $41,000 a year gain was price inflation rather than improvement in housing stock, that equates to $788 per week in capital gains income. This equates to 40% of the household income of the average home-owner (reinforcing the importance of asset price inflation).

The table below shows the impact of both the imputed rent and capital gains adjustments to the income of the average home owner-occupier. Total income for home-owners increases to $3008 per week, basically double that of the average renter.

Table showing Average Income + Net Imputed Rent + Capital Gain = Total Income

Clearly, the inclusion of non-cash housing income for owner-occupies significantly changes the relative incomes between the average home owner and average renter. It is another reason to argue that issues of housing affordability are felt most acutely by renters. While even on the raw ABS data it was possible to say that renters on average earned less than home-owners and spent proportionately more than home-owners on housing, the figures above show that the real situation is even more pronounced and more unequal.

Research Agenda

There is a caveat to the above because of the limitations of adding 3 separate averages (income, imputed rents, capital gains) and holding all other incomes/circumstances equal. It is order-of-magnitude approximation of the impact on inequality data, rather than a real estimation.

What is really required would be to use the ABS microdata to do this calculation for each household to produce a new total income data set. This could be made more complete by including asset price inflation of non-housing capital assets, and counter-balancing with an imputation for “social transfers in kind” – that is, the receipt of public services such as education, public health care, child care subsidies as well as a range of rebates and concessions.

From there a new income continuum could be constructed based on this total income, and then the standard income inequality measures could be applied to that. For instance, it would be possible to calculate a Gini coefficient, income percentile ratios and income shares for the top 1%, 5%, etc using the new income data.

Pretty clearly from the above, many home owner-occupiers would find themselves in much higher income brackets, while renters would be even more clustered in the lower income brackets. But I think that is the reality, that renters in effect have far lower incomes and much tougher cost of living struggles than home-owners (particularly non-mortgagee owners).

Obviously, the total spread of incomes would also be much greater, which I think would give a much truer picture of inequality in Australia.

Unfortunately though, while all this data is in the ABS Household Income and Wealth dataset, I don’t have the technical expertise to crunch the microdata numbers. Any volunteers?


[1]              The ABS presents this data separately, so I have combined them by multiplying the income by number of households in each category, and dividing the sum of both by the total number of households.

Talking about Public Housing: Political Economy, Neoliberalism or Welfare?

This article is a background to political economy, and why it matters in policy advocacy – in this case, in an approach to public housing. But it is also about political messaging, channelling Henry Lawson into a 2-minute housing video, and calling out neoliberalism.

This piece began as a background to the making of a short SACOSS video on why public housing matters, but ended up trying to explain what political economy is and what it offers to (and challenges in) social change advocacy.

Public housing matters.
South Australia needs more of it.
A link to the video is in the text below

Political Economy

The doyen of Australian political economy, Frank Stilwell describes the political economy approach as having four key features (in contrast to mainstream neoclassical economics). Political economy has:

  • A central focus on inequality
  • A pluralist method engaging different economic traditions
  • An interdisciplinary inclination
  • An ethical orientation in explicitly putting values, as well as facts, at the heart of analysis.

I plead guilty to all of the above. I would also note that the focus on inequality is a systemic one, not one based on individual differences, and that in a pluralist and interdisciplinary inclination, people’s stories matter. People are not simply economic actors or statistical units. They have unique stories and their representation matters.

This latter perspective is standard fare for advocacy in the charitable sector, but often at the expense of systemic analysis. This approach is encouraged by the demands of media and communications for powerful images and personal stories, but can end in disempowering “poverty porn” rather than social change.

But how do we do and communicate political economy, foregrounding the systemic nature of inequality, people’s experience and values?

Public Housing

This was the challenge for me at work earlier this year in developing a campaign call for a significant investment in public housing.

South Australia once had a national (and even international) leading public housing system, but over the last twenty plus years it has been diminished by aging stock and the sell-off of houses and land. Where public housing tenants made up 44% of renters in 1994, and 12% of the total housing market, in 2020 those numbers had reduced to 17% of renters and less than 5% of the total housing market (ABS data).

Unfortunately, the need for public housing had not diminished in that time. At 30 June 2020, the public housing waiting list was over 17,000 applicants – equivalent to 53% of total public housing stock (Productivity Commission data).

This decline and deficit was not an accident. It was driven by government policy and a significant ideological change in seeing public housing as a last-resort welfare measure (at best), or at worst simply overly expensive and counter-productive. This contrasts with the earlier vision of public housing as a market intervention at scale which reduces housing costs for all by increasing supply – a piece of public capital conditioning the private rental market.

In an era of neoliberal dominance where economists and governments had already decided that public housing is old-fashioned and a burden on the taxpayer, we were told it was best to highlight the waiting list and identify people/groups in need that were missing out. To appeal to sympathy in telling those personal/representational stories of stress and homelessness.

This approach ticks the box of a values-based policy, and it is a much easier policy and communication ask. With it, perhaps we could eek out some investment to house some more vulnerable people. But it would takes us back to the neoliberal frame of public housing as a welfare measure – the very approach which is part of the problem.

Economic Approaches to Public Housing

To develop this argument more, I again borrow from Frank Stilwell, in particular his categorisation of modern economic thought into conservative, liberal and radical schools.

In this framework, a conservative economic view sees a housing stress and homeless as an individual issue and government intervention in the housing market as counter-productive. Such intervention competes with productive capital and stops the market’s efficient allocation of housing. I know the theory, but personally, I just can’t see that the problem with Australia’s insane housing market is too much public housing!

A liberal approach might see homelessness as a market failure requiring intervention – for instance, subsidies or supports for individuals. While such interventions may be useful, by the nature of the underlying analysis, they are narrow in their focus and constrained within a market framework.

A more radical political economic approach would see housing stress and homelessness as systemic and relating to more than market supply and demand – a problem that also encompasses income, geography and infrastructure, cultural expectations, competing property rights, and entrenched and reinforcing patterns of inequality.

If this political economy analysis is correct, then it is easy to see how the provision of public housing at scale will help address the problem. Beyond just the provision of housing to those in need, it puts supply into the market creating downward pressure on all rents. It also provides for a different property regime (public rather than private ownership) where tenants have more rights through rent capping and tenancy protections. In contrast to fixed term private leases, public housing also provides a security of tenure and a permanency that challenges a cultural perception that renting is simply a pathway to the preferred status of home-ownership.

That is why public housing is important – and why ideology matters. The different ideological assumptions and analyses drive policy. And in this case, arguably the dominant schools of thought simply don’t have the breath of focus or the scale to address problems of housing stress and homelessness.

Henry Lawson and the video

And so, we arrived at the point of how to sell a political economy perspective on public housing. A short video would be nice!

Enter Henry Lawson. From my childhood I remember the great Australian poet’s “Faces in the Street”:

They lie, those who tell us in a loud decisive tone
That want is here a stranger, and that misery’s unknown;
For where the nearest suburb and the city proper meet
My window-sill is level with the faces in the street —
Drifting past, drifting past,
To the beat of weary feet —
While I sorrow for the owners of those faces in the street
.

I wanted to channel that anger, the personalness of it, into a systemic ask that was not about poverty pornography or a charitable helping of the unfortunate. But I also knew that Lawson’s Red Revolution’s marching feet was probably not a winning argument!

So, I drafted words, and my colleague put music and images to create a short video. Thanks to her, it turned out to be much more than I anticipated.

It remains an amateur production with basic technology and limited resources. And it is a short piece which can’t do the full political economic analysis. But as a prototype, from my point of view it does a few things of particular interest/importance:

  • It uses the sympathy-inducing images and music of a charitable fundraising video to go in a different direction
  • The emotional sadness is not just about the plight of individuals, but about a loss of common wealth (named as such) and the implications of that
  • At the point where the “you can help” fundraising ask would normally come, it instead names and shames government strategies and calls out politicians, think-tanks and the ideology that is to blame
  • The warm inner glow of hope at the end is for government/community action, not an individual gift or act of charity.

You can view the video here.

It is for others to judge whether the video is successful in making its point, or ticks all the boxes of a political economic analysis, or is useful as a communications tool. But regardless of the video, I remain convinced that the key issues around housing and homelessness (and much more) are ideological and political-economic, not ones of charity or welfare provision.

With apologies to Mr Lawson:

And so ’twill be while e’er the world goes rolling round its course,
The warning pen shall write in vain, the warning voice grow hoarse,
But not until a city feels political economy’s beat
Shall its sad people miss awhile the terrors of the street —
The dreadful everlasting strife
For scarcely clothes and meat
In that pent track of living death — the city’s cruel street.

Thomas Piketty, Councils of Social Service and Equality Advocacy

This piece considers the implications of the writings of Thomas Piketty for the work of the Councils of Social Service in Australia, but it is also relevant to other organisations and individuals fighting inequality.

Picture of two books:
Capital in the Twenty-First Century; and
Capital and Ideology
Implications for Councils of Social Service

I have summarised Piketty’s major work in a separate article, and those who are unfamiliar with his work may want to read that first. Here I draw on my understandings of Piketty to challenge some familiar assumptions, data and policy prescriptions.

WHO AND WHY

Thomas Piketty became a “rock star” economist after the publication of his ground-breaking Capital in the Twenty-First Century in 2013/14. The book provided a macro-economic analysis of issues raised by the political mobilisations of the Occupy movements of the previous decade, and it helped put questions of inequality on the cultural and political agenda around the world.

The book contains new intellectual and data tools (resourced and built upon by a team of academics across a range of countries and presented in the World Inequality Database). It is also highly critical of the official data produced by agencies like the ABS and relied on by many of us. For this reason, it is a body of work we need to engaged with.

Piketty’s work was decried by right-wing think tanks (e.g. the Free Market Foundation, and the Cato Institute), but also threatened to be banned in China. And perhaps most famously, alongside an obsessive array of data, he used the nineteenth century novels of Jane Austen and Honore de Balzac as evidence of inequality.

What could be more inviting?

FOCUS ON WEALTH

Much of the public discussion of poverty, cost-of-living, concessions and income support (including my own work at SACOSS) focuses on inequality of income. However, Piketty’s work demands a new focus on wealth accumulation and inequality. His data highlights inequality of wealth, while the famous r>g formulation focuses on the role of capital/wealth in driving income inequality.

recent study by Lisa Adkins and others builds on Piketty’s argument to argue that asset price inflation means that capital gains, capital income and inter-generational transfers are the preeminent drivers of inequality. This is important because those gains are mostly within the sphere of capital ownership. They may not show up as income at all.

It is well-known that inequality of wealth is generally greater than inequality of income, but the above suggests that a focus on income inequality may underestimate the true extent of economic inequality and miss key drivers of it.

Beyond mapping inequality, a focus on wealth is important because ABS data shows that there are significant differences in where particular households sit on wealth and income stratifications:

  • Only 35% of households in the lowest income quintile are also in the lowest wealth quintile, 23% have average wealth (home-owning pensioners?) and 7.3% have high wealth;
  • 42% of households in the highest income quintile are also high-wealth households – meaning that nearly 60% do not have high wealth.

Some recent SACOSS work has also shown significant differences between the expenditure patterns of households on essentials like water and public transport depending on whether their position is measured by income or wealth.

Insurance is another example of where expenditure is regressive in relation to income, that is, a proportionately bigger imposition on low-income households, but different when looking at households based on wealth. When considering income, making insurance cheaper (for instance by removing stamp duty on policies) looks like a good policy – and one that has been contemplated by SACOSS. However, such a policy will primarily result in a windfall for higher wealth households who have more to insure and proportionately higher insurance expenditures. For this reason, SACOSS has opted to call for an insurance concession for low-income households.

Similarly, policies that provide grants or subsidies to landlords for energy efficiency investments (as advocated in ACOSS’ NLEPP) are good in the income frame as they can lower energy bills for low-income tenants. However, such policies may also increase wealth inequality by increasing the value of the property and the wealth of the landowner.

In short, with an exclusive focus on income, we may be advocating and getting benefits for those who are financially well off, or we may not be targeting supports to where they are most needed.

DATA ISSUES

Even where the focus is on income, Piketty’s work raises questions about the data we use to categorise and measure income inequality. He argues that the household survey-data used in official measures of inequality is flawed both in collection method and categorisation. For instance, he suggests results vary if weekly, monthly or yearly income is used, while ratios between percentiles are volatile and surveys tend to significantly underestimate the income and wealth of the highest percentiles.

For this reason, Piketty prefers tax data and expresses inequality as a share of total income/wealth, rather than as the percentile ratios or Gini coefficients (found in ABS data). As per my previous post here, I also think the income share methodology is more versatile in that it can be applied to other areas such as gender. Indeed, the World Inequality database now includes this as part of its Australian data.

Piketty also suggests that the classification of households into quintiles is flawed. It suggests an even stratification of households and significantly fails to account for the massive increases in income and wealth in the top 10%, 1% or even 0.1% – and the power they exercise as a class. Instead he proposes a classification of classes defined as:

  • Lower = bottom 50% of income or wealth
  • Middle = from the 50th to 90th percentile of income of wealth
  • Upper = top 10%, which includes the “dominant class” which are the top 1%.

He admits this is somewhat arbitrary, but the lower bracket accounts for very little of society’s income or wealth, and the definition of middle is close to common usage of people who are doing better than most, but not the elite.

ACOSS’ flagship inequality report uses similar categorisations for wealth, but not for income. Other work around the network of Councils of Social Service (e.g. SACOSS cost of living reports) also uses income quintiles which may hide the real distributional dynamics. This is often because of the limitations of the data published by the ABS, but where there is the opportunity to use microdata to produce our own statistics, we should not be bound by ABS categories.

POLICY

The final chapter of Piketty’s second great tome, Capital and Ideology, outlines policy proposals which arise from his analysis. All reflect a base understanding that inequality should be limited and that to do this, we need to think about wealth as temporary and social, not a permanent and inalienable individual right. He proposes a number of large-scale policies or directions to limit inequality, including:

  • Co-management and power-sharing within corporations
  • Progressive income taxes and a basic income provision
  • Progressive annual wealth tax
  • Progressive inheritance taxes
  • Universal capital endowments of $100k or more paid to 25-ish year olds (and taxed back over time)
  • A public register of assets to facilitate greater transparency of wealth
  • A constitutional principle of fiscal justice based on non-regressivity and the publication of information on how tax is apportioned among the population
  • A progressive carbon tax
  • A just distribution of educational investment
  • Replacing tax deductions for political and charitable giving with funding vouchers for people to allocate to their preferred charities.
  • Transnational democracy and new global institutions.

The tax policies are obviously difficult to achieve politically, but go well beyond the timid tax changes the Councils of Social Service often champion. Apart from some mischievous SACOSS mentions of inheritance taxes, changes to negative gearing and capital gains tax are about as bold as we get (see for instance, ACOSS Budget Priorities, Section 10). These proposals are certainly steps in the right direction – but they are a long way short of annual wealth taxes. However, the power of Piketty’s historical and comparative analysis is that none of the big tax policies are utopian dreams. They all have existed at different times and/or currently exist in different places.

The universal capital endowment is more speculative. While I can see how it flows from the analysis, I worry about the implications for those who through fate/sickness/whatever don’t make the most of that endowment. Having had their perceived chance, will they simply be left behind with no support/sympathy?

Similarly, while in a previous post I have recommended removing tax deductions for charitable donations, I fear the alternative Piketty proposes. He proposes a voucher scheme where everyone can vote an allocation of money. But based on some local examples of where South Australians were asked to vote funding for neighbourhood projects, it is easy to see that such a scheme may simply lead to a populist contest where money does not go to where it is most needed.

THE ULTIMATE QUESTION

However, the quibbles above are relatively trivial issues for what are big proposals for broad policy directions. And beyond the individual proposals, Piketty’s work prompts one big final question: in the face of the macro-processes that are driving inequality, is the scale of change we often work at really going to make a dent on rising inequality?

I suspect not, but that is the ultimate challenge of Piketty’s work. It is a theme I will return to in future posts.

The Gender Wage Share – a $200bn gap

It seems to me to be an important fact that men receive $4bn a week more than women in the Australian labour market. This is the aggregate of the gender wage gap, but at $200bn a year it represents more than a gap in individuals’ earnings. It is a significant macroeconomic flow shaping both the economy and gender relations.

The Gender Wage Share in the Australian Labour Market
Men 62%
Women 38%

The Gender Wage Gap

The gender wage gap is a common measure of the difference between the average earnings of women and men in the workforce. It is generally expressed as a percentage of men’s earnings based on average total remuneration for full-time workers (a gap of 20.1%), full-time base salary (15%) or full-time average weekly earnings (14.2%) (WGEA data).

These measures are all based on full-time work. This is useful for comparing like-with-like (i.e. full time work) and can be important for highlighting differences in pay rates with women on average in less senior jobs and clustered in low paid jobs and industries. However, the full-time data ignores the actual work of just under half of the female workforce where around 45% of female jobs are part-time. Further, given that only 19% of male jobs are part-time, the focus on full time work centres and normalises male-work patterns and underestimates the differences in wages actually taken home.

These problems are corrected somewhat by calculating the gender wage gap based on the average weekly earnings of all workers. This blows the gender wage gap out to 31.3% because women are not only being paid less by a straight comparison (full-time earnings), they are working fewer hours so their average earnings are lower. Yet this adjustment only goes part of the way to recognising differences in labour force participation because the average weekly earnings do not tell us how many men or women are earning that income.

It would be theoretically possible to have an economy with no gender wage gap, but very few women employed. Indeed, if there were no women employed there would be no gender wage gap!

Alternatively, (and more realistically), women’s participation in the labour force may increase over time, which would be important in terms of the income, independence and economic power of women. However, if that increased participation simply replicates existing patterns then the gender wage gap data would remain unchanged.

The gender wage gap does not tell us how many people are impacted by the gap.

Gender Wage Share

Alongside these disaggregated averages and the expression of the gender wage gap in individual terms, I think it is important to record and express the aggregate outcome of the gender wage gap. This can be done by calculating the share of the total wages pool taken home by men and women. This will be a function of both earnings and participation and is used in the United Nations’ Gender Development Index.

The calculation in the UN index is complicated by the need to ensure international comparability, but in Australia the gender wage share can be calculated fairly easily. Using the ABS Labour Force and Average Weekly Earnings data, it is simply a matter of multiplying the average male wage by the number of male workers and the average female wage by the number of female workers. This gives an aggregate wage pool, and the male and female share of that pool. The table below shows the data for May 2021.

Data table showing female and make no. of employees, average weekly earnings, and difference and share of total wage pool.

There are caveats on this data in broader gender terms given that it relates to labour earnings only, and does not include investment or other income. Nor does it deal with the distribution of non-market production income, or the redistribution of wage income within households, or the range of other inequalities which are tied up in wage gaps.

However, wages are the main source of income for most Australian households, and the data above shows that women take home 38.5% of the total wages pool, a gap of 23 percentage points to the male share – or 11.5 points to an equal share.

But for me, the standout figure is the differential in total earnings of $4bn a week between men and women. That is, the ABS data shows that in any week men as a group earned around $4bn a week more than women as group.

To put that in perspective, it is over $200bn a year – an annual figure which is about the same size as the entire federal government expenditure on social security (Commonwealth Budget Paper No.1, Statement 6, Table 3).

In a recent submission to the Federal Government’s review of the Workplace Gender Equity Agency (WGEA), I contrasted this difference wage share with the annual budget of the agency. Obviously responsibility for addressing the gap in women’s wages and workforce participation does not lie solely with the WGEA, but it seems fairly optimistic to expect an expenditure of $6m to have much impact on a $200bn problem (quite apart from the limitations of the liberalism of the agency – which I did not mention in the submission!).

Macroeconomics

But beyond the individualism of liberal workplace strategies, understanding the quantum of the difference in the gender share of wages is important because of its macroeconomic reproductive role. I noted above that $200bn a year was roughly equivalent to the entire federal government expenditure on social security. It is also around ten times the size of the entire South Australian state budget.

It would seem fairly uncontroversial to say that the social security system and state governments have an important role in total income distribution, and in the stability, direction and reproduction of the economy and society. Could we not then also see that a $200bn a year income differential between men and women is an important income distribution in itself? And that it has a role in the reproduction of society – and specifically the gendered inequalities across society?

For those familiar with structural analysis, this should seem logical. But for those with a more individualist starting point, it may be challenging to posit gender groups as collective economic entities. After all, the social security system or a state government are institutions with formal rules, lines of authorities and someone in charge, whereas “men as a group” or “women as a group” are just collections of individuals making their own decisions with no governing force or collective interest.

However, in macroeconomics we happily talk about a $120bn tourism industry, when it is a myriad of small and large operators competing to maximise their individual business profits. We talk about flows of money to and from a “finance sector” which is a range of entities responding to the savings made available by and the financial needs of individual actors outside of its realm. At a more abstract level, we lionise the disparate decisions of many people into a collective entity called “the market”, so the concept of women or men as a group should not be too much of a stretch.

There are of course differences within gender categories, issues of intersectionality and critiques of such a binary construction of gender. These are big and important issues, but beyond the scope of this post. My point here is simply that if we are to talk about a gender wage gap, then it seems reasonable to also talk about it at a collective and aggregated level.

At this aggregate level, the shares of total wages going to men and to women, and the substantial difference between the two is important because money is not neutral, or simply a conveniently exchange mechanism. It is a store of wealth and an enabler of access to goods and services.

It matters to gender relations and the structures of society that men as a group have access to $200bn a year more cash than women as a group (or that women’s access to that extra money is mediated by men at home or by the state at large). That money enables men as a whole to do more things (or more economically rewarded things) than women, to occupy public space and power, and to command greater aggregate purchasing power to be met by market production.

A gendered labour market not only reflects inequalities, it begets further inequality.

Concluding Directions

I am not claiming that gender differences are limited or reducible to the economic sphere, or determined by economic forces. But I am trying to move away from individualist economics, and in this instance, mainstream theories of the gender wage gap as being a result of differences in human capital or household income maximisation strategies. I am arguing for a more macro-level and structural analysis.

In a future post I may use the gender wage share data to track changes over time (spoiler: the female wage share has increased with greater labour market participation, but tracks a bit differently to the more traditional gender wage gap data). For now though, I am simply putting the $200bn figure out there and challenging anyone to say that an aggregate flow of that amount of money is not important.